$Unique_ID{how02112} $Pretitle{} $Title{History Of Monetary Systems Chapter III: Pound, Shillings And Pence} $Subtitle{} $Author{Del Mar, Alexander} $Affiliation{} $Subject{money roman coins system silver gold footnote weight ratio empire} $Date{} $Log{} Title: History Of Monetary Systems Book: Chapter III: Pound, Shillings And Pence Author: Del Mar, Alexander Chapter III: Pound, Shillings And Pence Chapter Contents This system appears in the Theodosian Code - Is probably older - Its essential characteristic is valuation by moneys of account - Advantages - Previous diversity of coins - Danger of the loss of numismatic monuments - Exportation of silver to India - Difficulty of enforcing contracts of coins of a given metal - pound as an instrument of taxation - As an historical clew - It always followed Christianity - Sidelights to history afforded by the three denominations - pound and the Feudal system - It saved the most precious monuments of antiquity from destruction - Artificial character of the system - Its earliest establishment in the provinces - In Britain - Interrupted in some provinces by barbarian systems - Its restoration proves the resumption of Roman government - This rule applied to Britain. Pound, Shillings And Pence Searching for the beginning of a custom is like tracing a river back to its source: we soon discover that it has not one source but many. When brevity is preferable to precision, it is sufficient if we follow an institution to its principal or practical source. We have elsewhere shown the marks of chronological stratification in Roman history - originally decimal and afterwards duodecimal - which resulted from a change that, it is assumed, took place in the method of measuring the solar circle. This, we are persuaded, was originally divided into ten parts, each of 36 degrees; hence the archaic Roman or Etruscan year of ten months, each of 36 days, and the week or nundinum of nine days. At a later period the zodiac was divided into twelve parts, each of 30 degrees, whence the year of twelve months, each of 30 days. ^1 In these two systems we have the basis of the decimal and duodecimal methods of notation, which are so strangely intermingled in all Roman numbers and proportions, and which also appear in L. s. d. Thus the number of solidi to the libra was five, and the number of sicilici to the libra twenty, both of which are decimal proportions. ^1 On the other hand, the number of denarii to the sicilicus was twelve, and the ratio between the metals was twelve, which is duodecimal. ^2 [Footnote 1: By some writers the year of 360 days has been erroneously called a lunar year, but in fact a year contains nearly thirteen lunar months. The year of twelve months was originally solar, and was always astrological. Many of the early institutes mentioned by Livy, Pliny, and Censorinus were evidently taken from the laws of conquered and obliterated Etruria, and falsely attributed to Romulus, Numa, and other creations of Roman fancy. Among these institutes was the change from ten months of 36 days to twelve months of 30 days to the year (Livy, i., 19).] [Footnote 1: The "pound" of money is to be discerned during the decay of Attic liberty. The Romans used the term "pondus" to mean 100 drachmas, and the Greeks used the "talenton" of money before them. Twenty drachmas (silver) equaled in value one stater, and five staters were valued at a talenton, which the Romans called a pondus. The Greek ratio was 10. Most of the confusion on this subject has resulted from the refusal of numismatic writers to recognize - what their own monetary systems of to-day attest - that every name of a weight also meant at the same time a sum of money, which had no relation to such weight. Humphreys, Chambers and Putnam all furnish confused references to the pondus of 100 drachmas. The Persians in the time of Cyrus appear to have had a system of L. s. d. very like what the Romans afterward had.] [Footnote 2: A remarkable custom, which, it may reasonably be conjectured, originated in the changed subdivision of the zodiac, prevailed among the Goths. With them the ten meant twelve, and an hundred was six score. The custom still prevails in Essex, Norfolk and Scotland (Sir Francis Palgrave, i. 97). Some vestige of the score system still lingers in the French names for numbers. Curiously enough, too, the method of counting by scores was employed by the Aztecs (Prescott, p. 35).] Those writers whose researches into monetary systems are bounded by the narrow conclusions of Adam Smith's "Wealth of Nations" or Tooke's "History of Prices" usually attribute the origin of L. s. d. to William the Norman or to Charlemagne, and their explanation of the system is commonly confined to that of the pound., which they regard as the symbol for a pound weight of silver, or else a pound weight of silver coins. The different books in which this delusion is repealed are probably sufficiently numerous to stock a good sized library; yet it can be demolished in a few words. Neither the contents of the Norman or Carlovingian nor of any other coins sustain this theory, neither is it sustained by the texts of the Carlovingian or any other period. The libra of money (not the whole triad of L. s. d.) is at least five hundred and may be fifteen hundred years older than Charlemagne, being clearly defined in the Theodosian Code (lib. xiii., tit. ii., II), of which the following is the text and literal translation: - "Ita ut pro singulis libris argenti quinos solidos inferat" - "So that for each libra of money five solidi are to be understood." ^1 This portion of the code is attributed by some commentators to the constitutions of Constantine, by others to a law of Honorius and Arcadius (A. D. 397); ^2 but, as shown elsewhere, the libra of five gold pieces is older than either. It was used for five gold aurei by Caligula, Probus and Diocletian. It frequently occurs in the texts of Valens, ^3 Arcadius and other sovereign-pontiffs of the fourth to the eighth century, where, except in one instance, it always means five solidi. According to Father Mariana ("De Ponderis et Mensures"), the sicilicus - known in a subsequent age as the gold shilling - was struck as early as the first century of our era, for he states that in his own collection were gold pieces of this weight, struck by Faustina, Augusta, Vespasian and Nero. Others of Justinian, weighing 16 grains, are now in the Madrid collection. The denarius of the early empire, of which 25 in value went to the aureus, tallied in weight, though not in fineness, with the half-aureus. In the reign of Caracalla 24 denarii went to the aureus, the ratio of value between the metals remaining unchanged. Such is briefly the genesis of L. s. d. [Footnote 1: It is from this passage in the Theodosian Code that the learned Boeckh, Rome d'Lisle, and Bodin regarded the libra as a weight, and deduced the supposed ratio between silver and gold of 14.4 to 1. It is needless to say that if the libra was a money of account and not a weight, the deduction is erroneous. There is no instance of such a ratio of 14 4, or thereabouts, in Roman or Greek history - a fact which by itself should have rendered these erudite persons more cautious. The Code of Justinian (liber. x., tit. lxxvi., de argenti pretio) also gives the ratio, "pro libra argenti, 5 solidi."] [Footnote 2: Queipo, ii., 56.] [Footnote 3: The cupidity of the Duke of Moesia induced him to withhold provisions from the Gothic refugees, whom Valens, the sovereign-pontiff, had permitted to enter that province, so that a slave (mancipium) was given by the Goths for a loaf of bread (unum panem) and ten libras (of money) for a carcass of meat (aut decem libras in unum carnem mercarentur). It is evident that ten libras meant precisely what the law declared it should mean, namely. 50 solidi (equal to the contents of about 32 English sovereigns), for ten pounds weight of gold would contain as much as 464 English sovereigns. Gibbon avoids the difficulty by saying "the word silver must be understood;" but such was not the custom of that time, any more than it is now. When silver was understood it meant money and not metal. Said the law: "So that for each libra (libris argenti) five solidi (of gold) are to be understood" (Jornandes, "De Getarum," c. xxvi.; Gibbon, ii., 597, 4 to ed.)] The translation of "argentum" into "money" needs no explanation to Continental readers, for in all the Continental languages - French, Spanish, Italian, etc. - "silver" means money. This custom is derived from the Romans of the Empire, with whom "argentum" meant money, as the following examples sufficiently prove: - Argentariae tabernae, bankers' shops (Livy); argentaria inopia, want of money (Plautus); argentarius, treasurer (Plautus); argentei sc. nummi, or money (Pliny, xvi., 3); ubi argenti venas aurique sequuntur (Lucretius, vi., 808); cum argentum esset expositum in aedibus (Cicero); emunxi argento senes (Terrence); concisum argentum in titulos faciesque minutas (Juvenal xiv., 291); tenue argentum venaeque secundae (ibid., ix., 31). The Romans in turn got this term from the ancient Greeks, whose literature they studied and whose customs they affected. One of the Greek names for money was "argyrion," from argyros, silver. The Hebrew word for money was caseph, literally silver, alluding to the coined shekels of the Babylonians. The same custom, i. e., using the term "silver" for money, is to be found in the most ancient writings of Egypt and India. In a letter of Honorius and Theodosius II. to the Prefect of Gaul, written in our year of 418, after suggesting the formation of a council to regulate the affairs of that province, the emperors proposed, in case its members failed to attend the meetings, to subject them to fines of three and five "libras of gold" each. It is evident that the "libras" here mentioned are moneys and not weights, for five Roman libras weight of gold are equal to the quantity contained in 232 English sovereigns of the present day, and this would have been a preposterously heavy mulct for mere non-attendance. On the other hand, a libra of account represented by five gold solidi, would not have contained more than one-fourteenth of this quantity of gold, and it is evident that this is what was intended. These researches into the origin of L. s. d. were necessary in order to determine its essential characteristics as a system of valuations and proportions. The names of the subdivisions of money have in all ages been used to denote the relative proportions or subdivisions of other measures, as of weight, area, capacity, etc., and it is this practice which is responsible for much of that confusion on the subject of money that distinguishes economical literature. For example, L. s. d. were at one time used as proportions of the pound weight for weighing bread, at another time as proportions of the acre for measuring land. In the former case L. represented a pound weight of bread, s. an ounce, etc.; in the latter L. meant one and a-half acres and d. a rod of land. ^1 Sir Francis Palgrave (i., 93) says that many instances of this practice are to be found in charters of the sixth century. The mischief of it lies in the insinuation it conveys that because a "pound" weight can be the unit, integer, or standard of weight, and a "pound" measure (one and a-half acres) can be the unit of superficial area, so a "pound" sum of money can be the unit of money, which in the last case is physically impossible. The unit of money can never be one "pound," but must necessarily be all the "pounds," under the same legal jurisdiction, joined together. In other words, the unit of money is and must necessarily be all money. ^1 [Footnote 1: Statute 51, Henry III. (1267); Fleetwood's "Chronicon Preciosum."] [Footnote 1: See chapter on this subject in the author's "Science of Money."] Taking the essential character of L. s. d. to be a system of valuation by moneys of account, as distinguished from a system of valuation by coins, it must have possessed merits that rendered its adoption highly necessary and advantageous. We shall find that this was actually the case. Previous to the adoption of L. s. d. there was commonly but one denomination of money and - except in the peculiar monetary system of the Roman Commonwealth - it usually related to an actual coin. With the Romans this coin was successively the ace, denarius, sesterce and aureus. Even when two of these kinds of coins circulated side by side - as the ace and the denarius, or the sesterce and aureus - sums of money were always couched in one denomination, never in both. We now say so many pounds and shillings and pence, perhaps combining some of each denomination in one sum; or we may say so many dollars and cents, or so many francs and centimes. Down to the era of L. s. d. the Romans, in expressing sums of money, only used one term. So long as only one or two or three kinds of coins were current at the same time, there was no inconvenience in this custom; but when coins came to be made of different sizes and weights and of several different metals - bronze, silver and gold - some of them of limited tender and highly over-valued, like the bronze coins of to-day, one term for money became inexact and inconvenient. This is one of the reasons that led to the adoption of L. s. d. In the last quarter of the third century the Roman empire was divided between four Caesars, to whom was afterwards added he whom Sir Francis Palgrave has rather effusively termed "our own Carausius." Even before this division took place, the diversity of bronze and silver coins was so great as to produce confusion. With four emperors almost daily adopting new designs for coins, and several thousand unauthorized moneyers expelled from Mount Caelius and other places to ply their trade in every province of the Roman empire, the confusion became intolerable. Without some device by aid of which this maddening variety of types and weights could be readily harmonized and valued, it became impossible to carry on the operations of trade. Such a device was L. s. d. The infinite diversity and number of local and imperial silver coins had long since broken down that fragment of the fiduciary system of money which was attempted to be revived by Augustus; it had effaced all the influence of mine-royalties; it had nullified all the effects of mint-charges and seigniorage. The relative value of coins, which Rome was formerly content to read in the edicts of her consuls or emperors, she was now almost compelled to determine with a pair of scales. The imperial government could scarcely have observed this symptom of popular distrust without grave concern. In proportion as such coins lost fiduciary value, and rested upon that of their metallic contents, so did the empire lose importance to the provinces and the proconsuls to the local chieftains. Furthermore, when money ceased to derive any portion of its value from limitation of issue or from sacerdotal and imperial authority, why might not the proconsuls feel at liberty to issue circulating money as well as the sovereign-pontiff? why not the under-lords as well as the proconsuls? why not foreigners as well as citizens? - why not anybody or everybody? Besides this, it is to be remembered that the coins of Rome were designed to illustrate its mythology and history, and that they constituted its most precious and enduring monuments. Upon them were stamped the story of its miraculous origin, the images of its gods, demi-gods and heroes, the symbols of its religion, the spirit of its laws, and the dates of its most glorious achievements. All these now threatened to disappear in the melting-pot. The monuments had come to be regarded only as so much bullion, and every provincial governor or barbarian king would be tempted to reduce them to metal, in order that, upon recoining them, his own upstart image might shine in the glass that had once reflected a Romulus, a Caesar, or an Augustus. There was but one way to stop such a calamity, and that way was monopoly of the coinage and arbitrary valuation; but this had to be done through some new device, for the old ones were worn out, and would be seen through and rejected at once. ^1 The efforts to save the old monuments would justify a slight discrimination of value at the outset in favor of certain precious issues, and this discrimination might be extended and enlarged as time went on. Rome had hitherto kept its most sacred numismatic monuments from the furnace by means of a golden myth, a fixed ratio, and the restriction of exports. Without disturbing either of these arrangements, it was now proposed to supplement them with the device of L. s. d. [Footnote 1: In a less superstitious age perhaps not even the device of L. s. d. would have allayed the fear that the valuations would be changed, or have kept the coins from the melting pot. But to the Romans that law was a sacred one, which forbade the melting down of old coins (Digest i., c. de Auri pub. prosecut.; lib. xii., 13; Camden, "Brit.," p. 105).] The diversity of coins, and the hope of restoring some of their lost fiduciary value, furnished reasons for the adoption of a triad of monetary terms, in the place of that single term in which the Romans had hitherto couched their valuations and contracts; but the same considerations do not explain why these denominations were essentially ideal ones, nor why they remain so still. The explanation is simple enough. It will be found in the physical impossibility of adding together quantities of various materials and producing a quotient of one material. If L. means a piece of gold, s. a piece of silver, and d. a piece of bronze, then as a matter of fact it is impossible to add them together and produce a sum which shall represent a quantity of any one of these metals. Hence these denominations are essentially ideal. However, as logic seldom stands in the way of practical legislation, we may be sure that it was not this difficulty which compelled the Romans, when they adopted L. s. d., to make them ideal moneys, or moneys of account, that would logically add together; it was the practical difficulty of enforcing contracts payable in coins of a particular metal. Numbers of the mine-slaves had revolted, or escaped, to swell the armies of the Goths and other malcontents; the produce of the Roman mines had become irregular; the oriental trade had absorbed vast quantities of silver. ^1 A contract to pay sesterces meant so many silver coins, and the name sesterce had been so long wedded to a silver coin that it was found easier to establish a new denomination than divorce sesterce from silver. The same may be said of the gold aureus. L. s. d. being imaginary moneys, might be represented by either gold, silver or bronze coins at pleasure of the government, and as best suited the convenience of the times or the equity of payments. ^1 [Footnote 1: Pliny, "Natural History," vi, 23, and xii., 18.] [Footnote 1: In 1604 the Chief Justices of England decided that L. s. d. were imaginary moneys, and meant concretely whatever coins the sovereign from time to time might decree they should mean. They deduced this conclusion not only from the spirit of the common, but also from the principles of the civil law; and there can be no doubt that such was its legal significance at the period of its original adoption in Rome (State Trials, ii, 114; Digest, xviii., II).] It is scarcely necessary to turn from the public to the private influences which urged the adoption of L. s. d. upon the imperial and pontifical mind. A monetary system which by insensible degrees might be made to slip away from all metallic anchorage or limitation, needed no further recommendation to a needy treasury. Yet it still had another one. The diversity of races that constituted the population of the Empire and a nascent feudal system both stood in the way of any uniform system of taxation, while the distance between Rome and the capital of each province greatly multiplied frauds upon the treasury, and threw too much power and profit in the hands of the provincial vicars or proconsuls and the greedy farmers of the revenues. The facility to regulate the value of various coins which the adoption of L. s. d. promised to afford, placed in the hands of the sovereign-pontiff the means of levying a tax that could neither be evaded nor intercepted. Thus many reasons and interests combined to recommend the system of L. s. d. It brought into harmony the diversity of coins and coinages; it promised to restore some of the lost value of bronze and silver coins, and to conserve or obliterate (at pleasure) the ancient and sacred types; it offered to remedy the difficulties produced by the irregular supplies of the mines, and by the heavy exports of silver to India; it placed a future choice of other remedies in the hands of the emperor; and, finally, it was competent, at a pinch, to solve the problem of suddenly recouping an empty treasury. Under the system of L. s. d. any coin or piece of money could be legalized or decried at pleasure of the government, and any value could be put upon it that seemed expedient or desirable. All that was needed was a brief edict of the supreme sovereign, and at once, with military precision, this or that piece of money took its allotted station among the L. s. d., and there it served in the capacity and with the rank assigned to it by its imperial master. ^1 [Footnote 1: On different occasions the same coin has ranked as a penny three-half-pence, two-pence, and even three-pence. A shilling was at one time represented by a gold coin, at another by a silver coin. Examples of this character often occur in the ordinances of the mediaeval kings of France; and there is reason to believe that the sovereign-pontiffs of Rome more than once altered the legal value of their silver and bronze issues.] In the fourth century the d. was represented by a silver coin, and the s. by a gold coin containing about 18 (afterwards 16) grains of fine gold, and the L. by five large solidi (afterwards called besants), each containing 72 (afterwards 64) grains of fine gold. If we follow the adoption of L. s. d. in the various provinces of Europe - for example, Gaul, Britain, Spain or Germany - it will be found that it never preceded, whilst it invariably followed, the establishment of Roman Christianity. It therefore furnishes a valuable guide to the date of such establishment, and to the restoration of Roman government. L. s. d. was adopted in Gaul by Clovis, in a part of England it was established by Ethelbert, whilst in other parts it was rejected by the unconverted Gothic kings, his contemporaries. ^2 So the Arian Goths of Spain, down to the close of Roderic's reign, refused both the Roman religion and the Roman system of money, and the Saxons would have none of either until Charlemagne bent their stubborn necks to the yoke of the Roman gospel. [Footnote 2: The name of the sicilicus, which is evidently derived either from the fourth of the aureus or else from the fifteen-grain gold pieces of Sicily, was applied to the Norse aurar in the laws of Ethelbert (Sections 33-35). From the context it is evident that fifty scats are less in value than three shillings, hence that the purely silver scat of five to the gold shilling was not yet in use, and that the scats alluded to were the old rude ones of composite metal, weighing 7 1/2 grains and upwards, and of varying and uncertain metallic contents. The shilling of Ethelbert's laws is the earliest mention of that coin in England. There was as yet no Norse analogue, either for the libra or the penny; in other words, there was no twelfth of the aurar nor any twenty-aurar piece, hence there was no further application of L. s. d. at that time to Gothic coins. The Roman "pounds, shillings and pence" had yet to be fully established in England. Some of the gold sicilici of the heretical Roger II., of Sicily, bear the legend in Arabic: "One God; Mahomet is His Prophet." On the other side is the phallic sign. A specimen, somewhat worn, weighed by the writer, contained 15 grains gross. These shillings were evidently copied from older Sicilian coins of the same weight and type.] Another valuable historical sidelight is derived from L. s. d. The arithmetical relations of these moneys of account were originally, but have not been always, 12 X 20 = 240. Sometimes they were 5 X 48 = 240, or 4 X 60 = 240, or even (exceptionally) 5 X 60 = 300. Whenever this is observed it affords a sure indication of grafting. The Gothic ratio between the precious metals was 8, the Arabian ratio 6 1/2, and the Roman ratio 12. Consequently, when the Roman arithmetical relations of L. s. d. were grafted on Gothic or Arabian, or Gothic-Arabian, monetary systems they had to be modified to suit the local valuation of gold and silver. ^1 For example, in the eighth century in Roman Christian Gaul (ratio of 12) it took 12 silver pence, each of 16 grains, to equal in legal value 1 gold sicilicus of similar weight, whilst in the Gothic parts of Britain, where the Arabian ratio prevailed (ratio of 6 1/ 2), 5 silver pence, each of 20 grains, sufficed; so that if, as convenience dictated, the newly introduced L. was still to consist of 240 pence, it would have to be valued at 48 shillings of account, and this was accordingly done. ^1 Modifications in the weights of the silver penny, and efforts to harmonize the two principal conflicting ratios - the Roman and Arabian - will explain, not only the remaining variations of L. s. d. above alluded to, but also many other obscure problems connected with the early monetary systems of England. [Footnote 1: The system of Offa, king of Mercia, was Gothic-Arabian, and, as is elsewhere shown, some of his coins had Arabian inscriptions upon them.] [Footnote 1: System of Ethelbert, king of Kent, 725-60.] We have seen how L. s. d. arose out of the circumstances of a decaying empire; we shall now see how it accommodated itself to those circumstances, so as to promote the very disease it was in part designated to remedy. The empire was falling to pieces, splitting into many parts. First, it had one Caesar, then two, three, four or more. Even when it got rid of its Thirty Tyrants, and reduced the number to six, the diversity of coins and coinages was too bewildering for practical purposes. To harmonize and regulate these coins, as well as for other reasons, L. s. d. was adopted. Yet by accommodating itself to a diversity of moneys, this system prevented the evil from righting itself through the simple and efficacious means of re-coinage. Dispensing with the necessity of uniformity, it encouraged heterogeneity by rendering it less intolerable, and thus facilitated that splitting up and subdivision of the coining authority which characterized the matured feudal system, and lent it strength and support. Devised in part to unify moneys and centralize authority, it became no insignificant aid to decentralization and feudalism. On the other hand, but for its influence the Roman coins, and with them the memories which they invoked and the sacred myths they perpetuated, would have been destroyed, and the modern world would have had to read the history of the past in the unmeaning baugs of Scandinavia, the saigas of Frakkland, or the composite scats of the Anglo-Saxon heptarchy. Returning to the historical clew afforded by the adoption of L. s. d., the reader will scarcely fail to have been impressed with the extreme artificiality of this system. Hundreds of books have already been written upon it, and hundreds more will probably yet be written upon it before its true character, mischievous bearing, and incongruity with the modern age of progress will be recognized and acted upon. Allusion is here made, not merely to a system of three denominations, as L. s. d., nor to a mingled bi-decimal and duodecimal notation, nor to its character as money of account, but to the mingling in this system of imperial with provincial and municipal or other coins; of seignioried with non-seignioried coins; of coins with various degrees of legal tender; of coins of local with others of extensive legal tender; of native with foreign coins made legal tender; of redeemable with non-redeemable coins; of governmental with private (bank) issues of various degrees of legal tender; and of non interest-bearing with interest-bearing legal-tender issues. In these respects and others the principles of all the monetary systems of the present day originated in the Roman imperial system of L. s. d., and so far as they follow it they interpose important obstacles to the practice of equity, the just diffusion of wealth, and the progress of civilization. ^1 [Footnote 1: "Science of Money," chapter vi.] The L. s. d. system was as much unfitted for the Gothic kingdoms or fiefs of the dark ages as it was suitable for the Empire. In a former work it was shown that there existed a natural harmony, or tendency toward harmony, between systems of government and systems of money, just as there is between social phases and language. For example, if one of the sentences of Cicero or Tacitus were imputed to a savage orator, no matter how eloquent or renowned, the unfitness of the phraseology, and its lack of harmony with the social phase of the speaker, would a once expose the blunder or imposture. Similarly, if an L. s. d. system of money were attributed to a tribe of Zulus, the incongruity of the collocation would immediately stamp it as untrue. For not only are three denominations of money too artificial a means of valuation to fall within the mental compass of a barbarian tribe, one of them (the L) was always an ideal money, and all of them were maintained, and could only be maintained, by a mint code of extreme complexity, and covering mining, minting, seigniorage, artificial ratio between the precious metals, and a hundred other subjects, concerning which neither Zulu nor Goth ever had a clear conception. For these various reasons the artificial system of L. s. d. furnishes an unerring clew to historical researches during the dark ages. In a previous chapter similar clews were found in the golden myth and the sacred ratio of twelve; in the present one we shall follow the clew of the three denominations. The text of the Theodosian Code implies the use of L. s. d. at Rome and in all the Christian provinces of the Empire. The non-Christian provinces were those parts of Gaul and Britain which, at the time of the promulgation of this code, were temporarily under the control of Anglo-Saxon, Frankish and other barbarian chieftains. The letter of Honorius and Theodosius II. (A. D. 418) implies the use of L. s. d. at that date in southern and perhaps central Gaul. From 496 to 561, during the governments of the Roman patricians Clovis and Clothaire I., the L. s. d. system was probably established throughout the whole of Gaul, except Brittany, Burgundy and Provence. The Roman coins found buried with the body of Childeric, ^1 and more especially the Roman offices and titles accepted by the Merovingian Frankish princes down to the sixth century, when image-worship was insisted upon, or, still worse, when the assassin Phocas was worshiped at Rome, imply the continuance of Roman government in Gaul until that period. After this time, and until the reign of Pepin, many of the provinces forgot their allegiance. ^2 Over and over again the Franks had professed and evinced their willingness to live under Roman law and Roman government, and they proved their sincerity and good faith in these professions by accepting Roman ecclesiastics as the administrators of that law and the representatives of that government. So long as Rome inculcated the worship of a heavenly deity the Franks continued loyal to the empire, but when the Roman pontiff fell at the feet of Phocas, and the detested religion of emperor-worship seemed about to be revived in the very fane of religion, they turned upon the Empire. ^3 From Theodebert to Pepin the Short the Roman monetary system was interrupted in Gaul. Its place was partly filled with a Frankish system, in which the relative value of gold and silver, no longer kept in place by the sacred myth of Rome, fell back to the old Druidical (and Etruscan) ratio, or else obeyed, to a certain extent, the influence of the Moslem mint-laws of Spain and Southern Gaul, for it became 1 to 10 instead of 1 to 8. The gold sou, or solidus, was valued in Merovingian laws at 40 silver deniers, or denarii; the little sou, or sicilicus, was valued in the same laws at 10 silver deniers, the sicilicus and denier containing the same weight of metal. The first fact is from the texts of the period, the last from the coins themselves. The establishment of this system was the mark of Frankish independence from the empire. It lasted about a century and a half; after that Gaul again became a Roman province. ^1 [Footnote 1: His tomb was opened in the seventeenth century (Morell, 67).] [Footnote 2: The Merovingians struck gold under authority of the Basileus until the reign of Theodebert, who struck gold for himself. Yet even after this period many of the Merovingians coined under authority of the Basileus.] [Footnote 3: Charlemagne, at the Council of Frankfort (794), denounced the worship of the imperial images.] [Footnote 1: The earliest rehabilitation of the Roman system appears in the capitulary of Pepin and Carloman, A. D 743, wherein the sol is valued at 12 deniers (Guizot, iii., 27).] In short, the monetary system of L. s. d. was established wherever Roman government prevailed - in Italy, Greece, Asia Minor, Armenia, Egypt, Carthage, Spain, Gaul, Britain and Germany. It was not established by any state or people not subject to Rome, never by the pagan Angles, Jutes, Saxons, Franks, Sclavs or Huns, and never by the Moslem, whether in Arabia, Egypt, Africa, Spain, France or Persia. After the dry bones of the sacred Empire fell into the hands of the Turks, in the fifteenth century, the latter, in order to accommodate their nummulary language, so far as practicable, to the customs of the conquered Greek provinces, employed the L. and the d. to mean - not indeed what they formerly meant - but something that suggested it, and this practice afterwards found its way into other provinces of Turkey; but it had no essential connection with the L. s. d. system, and employed only two denominations instead of the characteristic three. Although it is probable that the libra of money (not the L. s. d. system) continued to be used in the Roman cities of Britain from the Roman period down to the time when these cities fell into the hands of the Anglo-Saxons, we have no certain evidence of the fact. The earliest implication of the L. s. d. system in any document now extant occurs in the barbarian laws of Ethelbert, A. D. 561-616 (ss. 33-5), where certain fines are levied in shillings. No "libras" are mentioned; and no denarii for twelfths of the Norse aurar; ^1 hence no entire adoption of the system can be positively inferred. The shilling of Ethelbert was probably either a Latin name for a coin identical in weight with the Norse aurar, or an anachronism, inserted by copyists at a later date. ^2 In neither case would this text afford any certain indication when the L. s. d. system was re-introduced into Britain; and there is no other evidence that can be relied upon of an earlier date than the reign of Ina, which was toward the end of the seventh century. [Footnote 1: See Roman gold coin of Canterbury mentioned in my "Ancient Britain," ch. xix.] [Footnote 2: Bishop Fleetwood ("Chronicon Preciosum," pp. 52-4) gives examples from Brompton's translations of the laws of Ethelstan and Ina, in which the terminology and valuations of money were changed to suit the circumstances of the translator's times. Guerard and De Vienne give examples of similar alterations in the ancient texts of the Frankish, Lombardian, Frisian, and Burgundian codes of law.] Measured by the clew of L. s. d., the Anglo-Saxon chieftains interrupted the continuity of Roman government in some parts of Britain during an interval of more than two centuries, that is to say, from a date somewhat later than the edict of Arcadius and Honorius to the reign of Ina. In other parts there was scarcely any interval at all, for many of the Roman cities of Britain held out long after the legions departed, and even then, they capitulated on terms which involved, if they did not expressly admit, the imperial supremacy of Rome. So far as it goes, the clew of L. s. d. harmonizes with the myth of gold and the sacred ratio, and they all corroborate those other evidences which proclaim that except during a comparatively brief interval, which was probably no greater in Britain than in Gaul, the former remained a province of the empire from the reign of Claudius down to a much later period than is commonly supposed. ^1 [Footnote 1: Mr. Freeman deemed it probable that at the end of the sixth century there were still Roman towns in Britain tributary to the English chieftains, rather than occupied by them. Sir Francis Palgrave (i., vi.) extends the Roman occupation of some British cities down to the seventh century. Du Bos, Savigny, and Gibbon concur in a similar belief with regard to some of the cities of Gaul.]